The Question of Minorities The Moslem
League: Mr. M. A. Jinnah (Continued)
The chief Hjndu
communal organization is the Hindu Mahasabha, the counterpart of the Moslem
League, but relatively less important. It is as aggressively communal as the
League, but it tries to cover up its extreme narrowness of outlook by using
some kind of vague national terminology, though its out-look is more revivalist
than progressive. It is peculiarly unfortunate in some of its leaders who
indulge in irresponsible and
violent diatribes, as indeed do some of the Moslem League
leaders also. This verbal warfare, indulged in on both sides, is a constant
irritant. It takes the place of action.
The Moslem League's
communal attitude was often difficult and unreasonable in the past, but no less
unreasonable was the attitude of the Hindu Mahasabha. The Hindu minorities in
the Punjab and Sind, and the dominant Sikh group in the Punjab, were often
obstructive and came in the way of a settlement. British policy was to encourage
and emphasize these differences and to give importance to communal
organizations as against the Congress.
One test of the
importance of a group or party, or at any rate of its hold on the people, is an
election. During the general elections in India in 1937 the Hindu Mahasabha
failed completely; it was nowhere in the picture. The Moslem League did better
but on the whole its showing was poor, especially in the pre-dominantly Moslem
provinces. In the Punjab and Sind it failed completely, in Bengal it met with
only partial success. In the North-West Frontier Province Congress formed a
ministry later. In the Moslem minority provinces, the League met with greater
success on the whole, but there were also independent Moslem groups as well as
Moslems elected as Congressmen.
Then began a
remarkable campaign on behalf of the Moslem League against the Congress
governments in the provinces and the Congress organization itself. Day after
day it was repeated that the governments were committing 'atrocities' on the Moslems.
The governments contained Moslem ministers also but they were not members of
the Moslem League. What these 'atrocities' were it was not usually stated, or
some petty local incidents, which had nothing to do with the government, were
distorted and magnified. Some minor errors of some departments, which were soon
rectified, became 'atrocities'. Sometimes entirely false and baseless charges
were made. Even a report was issued, fantastic in its contents and having
little to do with any facts. Congress governments invited those who made the
charges to supply particulars for investigation or to come and inquire
themselves with government help. No one took advantage of these offers. But the
campaign continued unchecked. Early in 1940, soon after the resignation of the
Congress ministers, the then Congress president, Dr. Rajendra Prasad wrote to
Mr. M. A. Jinnah and also made a public statement inviting the Moslem League to
place any charges against the Congress governments before the federal court of
inquiry and decision. Mr. Jinnah declined this offer and referred to the
possibility of a Royal Commission being appointed for the purpose. There was no
question of any such commission being appointed and only the British Government
could do so. Some of the British governors, who had functioned during the
regime of the Congress governments declared publicly that they had found
nothing objectionable in the treatment of minorities. Under the Act of 1935
they had been especially empowered to protect minorities if any such need
arose.
I had made a close
study of nazi methods of propaganda Since Hitler's rise to power and I was
astonished to find something very similar taking place in India. A year later,
in 1938, when Czechoslovakia had to face the Sudetenland crisis, the nazi
methods employed there were studied and referred to with approval by Moslem
League spokesmen. A comparison was drawn between the position of Sudetenland
Germans and Indian Moslems. Violence and incitements in speeches and in some newspapers
became marked. A Congress Moslem minister was stabbed and there was no
condemnation of this from any Moslem League leader; in fact it was condoned.
Other exhibitions of violence frequently took place.
I was terribly
depressed by these developments and by the general lowering of the standards of
public life. Violence, vulgarity, and irresponsibility were on the increase,
and it appeared that they were approved of by responsible leaders of the Moslem
League. I wrote to some of these leaders and begged them to check this tendency
but with no success. So far as the Congress governments were concerned, it was
obviously to their interest to win over every minority or other group and they
tried hard to do so. Indeed complaints arose from some quarters that they were
showing undue favour to the Moslems at the expense of other groups. But it was
not a question of a particular grievance which could be remedied, or a
reasonable consideration of any matter. There was a regular campaign on the
part of members or sympathisers of the Moslem League to make the Moslem masses
believe that something terrible was happening and that the Congress was to
blame. What that terrible thing was nobody seemed to know. But surely there
must be something behind all this shouting and cursing, if not here then
elsewhere. During by-elections the cry raised was 'Islam in danger' and voters
were asked to take their oaths on the holy book to vote for the Moslem League
candidate.
All this had an
undoubted effect on the Moslem masses. And yet it is surprising how many
resisted it. The League won most by-elections, lost some; even when they won,
there was a substantial minority of Moslem voters who went against them, being
influenced more by the Congress agrarian programme. But for the first time in
its history the Moslem League got a mass back-ing and began to develop into a
mass organization. Much as I regretted what was happening, I welcomed this
development in a way as I thought that it might lead ultimately to a change in
the feudal leadership and that more progressive elements would come forward.
The real difficulty thus far had been the extreme political and social
backwardness of the Moslems which made them liable to exploitation by
reactionary leaders.
Mr. M. A. Jinnah himself
was more advanced than most of his colleagues of the Moslem League. Indeed he
stood head and shoulders above them and had therefore become the indispensable
leader. From public platforms he confessed his great dis-satisfaction with the
opportunism, and sometimes even worse failings, of his colleagues. He knew well
that a great part of the advanced, selfless, and courageous element among the
Mos-lems had joined and worked with the Congress. And yet some destiny or
course of events had thrown him among the very people for whom he had no
respect. He was their leader but he could only keep them together by becoming
himself a prisoner to their reactionary ideologies. Not that he was an
unwilling prisoner, so far as the ideologies were concerned, for despite his
external modernism, he belonged to an older generation which was hardly aware
of modern political thought or development. Of economics, which overshadow the
world to-day, he appeared to be entirely ignorant. The extraordinary occurrences
that had taken place all over the world since World War I had apparently had no
effect on him. He had left the Congress when the organization had taken a
political leap forward. The gap had widened as the Congress developed an
economic and mass outlook. But Mr. Jinnah seemed to have remained ideologically
in that identical place where he stood a generation ago, or rather he had gone
further back, for now he condemned both India's unity and demo-cracy. 'They
would not live,' he has stated, 'under any system of government that was based
on the nonsensical notion of western democracy.' It took him a long time to
realize that what he had stood for throughout a fairly long life was
nonsensical.
Mr. Jinnah is a lone
figure even in the Moslem League, keep-ing apart from his closest co-workers,
widely but distantly respected, more feared than liked. About his ability as a
politician there is no doubt, but somehow that ability is tied up with the
peculiar conditions of British rule in India to-day. He shines as a
lawyer-politician, as a tactician, as one who thinks that he holds the balance
between nationalist India and the British power. If conditions were different
and he had to face real problems, political, and economic, it is difficult to
say how far his ability would carry him. Perhaps he is himself doubtful of
this, although he has no small opinion of himself. This may be an explanation
for that subconscious urge in him against change, to keep things going as they
are, and to avoid discussion and the calm consideration of problems with people
who do not wholly agree with him. He fits into this present pattern; whether he
or anybody else will fit into a new pattern it is difficult to say. What
passion moves him, what objective does he strive for? Or is it that he has no
dominating passion except the pleasure he has in playing a fascinating
political game of chess in which he often has an opportunity to say 'check'? He
seems to have a hatred for the Congress which has grown with the years. His
aversions and dislikes are obvious, but what does he like? With all his
strength and tenacity, he is a strangely negative person whose appropriate
symbol might well be a 'no'. Hence all attempts to understand his positive
aspect fail and one cannot come to grips with it.
Since British rule came to India, Moslems have produced few
outstanding figures of the modern type. They have produced some remarkable men
but, as a rule, these represented the continuation of the old culture and
tradition and did not easily fit in with modern developments. This incapacity
to march with the changing times and adapt themselves culturally and other-wise
to a new environment was not of course due to any innate failing. It derived
from certain historical causes, from the delay in the development of a new
industrial middle class, and the excessively feudal background of the Moslems,
which blocked up avenues of development and prevented the release of talent. In
Bengal the backwardness of the Moslems was most marked, but this was obviously
due to two causes: the destruction of their upper classes during the early days
of British rule, and the fact that the vast majority were converts from the
lowest class of Hindus, who had long been denied opportunities of growth and
progress. In northern India the cultured upper-class Moslems were tied up with
their old traditional ways as well as the land system. In recent years there
has been a marked change and a fairly rapid development of a new middle class
among Indian Moslems, but even now they lag far behind Hindus and others in
science and industry . The Hindus are backward also, sometimes even more
hide-bound and tied up with traditional ways of thought and practice than the
Moslems, but nevertheless they have produced some very eminent men in science,
industry, and other fields. The small Parsee community has also produced
outstanding leaders of modern industry. Mr. Jinnah's family, it is interesting
to note, was originally Hindu.
Both
among Hindus and Moslems a good deal of talent and ability has in the past gone
into government service, as that was the most attractive avenue open. With the
growth of the political movement for freedom, that attraction became less, and
able, earnest, and courageous persons were drawn into the Congress. Thus many
of the best types of Moslems came in to it. In more recent years young Moslems
joined the socialist and communist parties also. Apart from all these ardent
and progressive persons, Moslems were very poor in the quality of their leaders
and were inclined to look to government service alone for advancement. Mr.
Jinnah was a different type. He was able, tenacious, and not open to the lure of office, which had been such a failing of so many others. His position in
the Moslem League, therefore, became unique and he was able to command the
respect which was denied
to many others prominent in the League. Unfortunately his tenacity prevented
him from opening his mind to any new ideas, and his unquestioned hold on his
own organization made him intolerant both of his own dissidents and of other
organizations. He became the Moslem League. But a question arose: As the League
was becoming a mass organization, how long could this feudal leadership with
outmoded ideas continue?
When
I was Congress president, I wrote to Mr. Jinnah on several occasions and
requested him to tell us exactly what he would like 11s to do. I asked him what
the League wanted and what its definite objectives were. I also wanted to know
what the grievances of the League were against the Congress govern-ments. The
idea was that we might clarify matters by corres-pondence and then discuss
personally the important points that had arisen in it. Mr. Jinnah sent me long
replies but failed to enlighten me. It was extraordinary how he avoided telling
me, or anyone else, exactly what he wanted or what the grievances of the League
were. Repeatedly we exchanged letters and yet always there was the same
vagueness and inconclusiveness and I could get nothing definite. This surprised
me very much and made me feel a little helpless. It seemed as if Mr. Jinnah did
not want to commit himself in any way and was not at all eager for a
settlement.
Subsequently
Gandhiji and others amongst us met Mr. Jinnah, several times. They talked for
hours but never got beyond a preliminary stage. Our proposal was that
representatives of the Congress and the League should meet and discuss all
their mutual problems. Mr. Jinnah said that this could only be done after we
recognized publicly that the Moslem League was the sole representative organization
of the Moslems of India, and the Congress should consider itself a purely Hindu
organization. This created an obvious difficulty. We recognized of course the
importance of the League and because of that we had approached it. But how
could we ignore many other Moslem organizations in the country, some closely
associated with us? Also there were large numbers of Moslems in the Congress
itself and in our highest executive. To admit Mr Jinnah's claim meant in effect
to push out our old Moslem colleagues from the Congress "and declare that
the Congress was not open to them. It was to change the fundamental character
of the Congress, and from a national organization, open to all, convert it into
a communal body. That was inconceivable for us. If the Congress had not already
been there, we would have had to build up a new national organization open to
every Indian.
We could not
understand Mr. Jinnah's insistence on this and refusal to discuss any other matter. Again we could only conclude
that he did not want any settlement, nor did he want to commit himself in any
way. He was satisfied in letting matters drift and in expecting that he could
get more out of the British Government this way.
Mr. Jinnah's demand
was based on a new theory he had recently propounded—that India consisted of
two nations, Hindu and Moslem. Why only two I do not know, for if nationality
was based on religion, then there were many nations in India. Of two brothers
one may be a Hindu, another a Moslem; they would belong to two different
nations. These two nations existed in varying proportions in most of the
villages of India. They were nations which had no boundaries; they overlapped.
A Bengali Moslem and a Bengali Hindu living together, speaking the same
language, and having much the same traditions and customs, belonged to
different nations. All this was very difficult to grasp; it seemed a reversion
to some medieval theory. What a nation is it is difficult to define. Possibly
the essential characteristic of national consciousness is a sense of belonging
together and of together facing the rest of mankind. How far that is present in
India as a whole may be a debatable point. It may even be said that India
developed in the past as a multinational state and gradually acquired a
national consciousness. But all these are theoretical abstractions which hardly
concern us. To-day the most powerful states are multi-national, but at the same
time developing a national consciousness, like the U.S.A. or the U.S.S.R.
From Mr. Jinnah's two-nation theory developed the conception
of Pakistan, or splitting up of India. That, of course, did not solve the
problem of the 'two nations,' for they were all over the place. But that gave
body to a metaphysical conception. This again gave rise to a passionate
reaction among many in favour of the unity of India. Ordinarily national unity
is taken for granted. Only when it is challenged or attacked, or attempts are
made to disrupt it, is unity really appreciated, and a positive reaction to
maintain it takes place. Thus sometimes attempts at disruption actually help to
weld that unity.
There
was a fundamental difference between the outlook of the Congress and that of
the religious-communal organizations. Of the latter the chief were the Moslem
League and its Hindu counterpart, the Hindu Mahasabha. These communal organizations,
while in theory standing for India's independence, were more interested in
claiming protection and special privileges for their respective groups. They
had thus inevitably to look to the British Government for such privileges, and
this led them to avoid conflict with it. The Congress outlook was so tied up
with India's freedom as a united nation that everything else was secondary, and
this meant ceaseless conflict or friction with the British power.
Indian nationalism,
as represented by the Congress, opposed British imperialism. The Congress had
further developed agrarian, economic, and social programmes. Neither the Moslem
League nor the Hindu Mahasabha had ever considered any such question or
attempted to frame a programme. Socialists and communists were,' of course,
intensely interested in such matters and had their own programmes, which they
tried to push in the Congress as well as outside.
There was yet another
marked difference between Congress policy and work and those of the
religious-communal organizations. Quite apart from its agitational side and its
legislative activity, when such existed, the Congress laid the greatest stress
on certain constructive activities among the masses. These activities
consisted in organizing and developing cottage industries, in raising the
depressed classes, and later in the spread of basic education. Village work
also included sanitation and some simple forms of medical relief. Separate
organizations for carrying on these activities were created by the Congress,
which functioned apart from the political plane, and which absorbed thousands
of whole-time workers and a much larger number of part-time helpers. This quiet
non-political, constructive work was carried on even when political activities
were at a low ebb; but even this was suppressed by Government when there was
open conflict with the Congress. The economic value of some of these activities
was questioned by a few people, but there could be no doubt of their social
importance. They trained a large body of whole-time workers in intimate touch
with the masses, and produced a spirit of self-help and self-reliance among the
people. Congressmen and women also played an important part in trade union and
agrarian organizations, actually building up many of these. The largest and
best-organized trade union—that of the Ahmedabad textile industry—was started
by Congressmen and worked in close co-operation with them.
All these activities
gave a solid background to Congress work, which was completely lacking in the
religious-communal organizations. These latter functioned on the agitational
plane only by fits and starts, or during elections. In them also was lacking
that ever-present sense of risk and personal danger from government action
which Congressmen had almost always to face. Thus, there was a far greater
tendency for careerists and opportunists to enter these organizations. The two
Moslem organizations, the Ahrars and the Jamiat-ul-Ulema, however, suffered
greatly from governmental repression because politically they often
followed the same line as the Congress.
The Congress
represented not only the nationalist urge of India, which had grown with the
growth of the new bourgeoisie, but also, to a large extent, proletarian urges
for social change. In particular,
it stood for revolutionary agrarian changes. This sometimes
produced inner conflicts within the Congress, and the landlord class and the
big industrialists, though often nationalistic, kept aloof from it for fear of
socialistic changes. Within the Congress, socialists and communists found a
place and could influence Congress policy. The communal organizations, whether
Hindu or Moslem, were closely associated with the feudal and conservative
elements and were opposed to any revolutionary social change. The real conflict
had, therefore, nothing to do with religion, though religion often masked the
issue, but was essentially between those who stood for a nationalist—democratic—socially
revolutionary policy and those who were concerned with preserving the relics of
a feudal regime. In a crisis, the latter inevitably depend upon foreign support
which is interested in preserving the status quo.
The beginning of
World War II brought an internal crisis which resulted in the resignation of
the Congress governments in the provinces. Before this occurred, however, the
Congress made another attempt to approach Mr. M. A. Jinnah and the Moslem
League. Mr. Jinnah was invited to attend the first meet-ing of the Congress
Executive after the commencement of the war. He was unable to join us. We met
him later and tried to evolve a common policy in view of the world crisis. Not
much progress was made but nevertheless we decided to continue our talks.
Meanwhile the Congress governments resigned on the political issue which had
nothing to do with the Moslem League and the communal problem. Mr. Jinnah,
however, chose that moment for a fierce attack on the Congress and a call on
his League for the observance of a 'Day of Deliverance' from Congress rule in
the provinces. He followed this up by very un-becoming remarks on Nationalist
Moslems in the Congress and especially on the Congress president, Maulana Abul
Kalam Azad, who was greatly respected among Hindus and Moslems alike. The 'Day
of Deliverance' was rather a flop and counter demonstrations among Moslems took
place in some parts of India. But it added to bitterness and confirmed the
conviction that Mr. Jinnah and the Moslem League under his leadership had no
intention whatever of coming to any settlement with the Congress, or of
advancing the cause of Indian freedom. They preferred the' existing situation.[
After I had finished writing this book, I read a book by a Canadian scholar, Wilfrid
Cantwell Smith, who has spent some years in Egypt and India. This book, which
is called 'Modern Islam in India—A Social Analysis, (Lahore, 1943), is an able
analysis and careful survey of the development of ideas among Indian Moslems
since the Indian Mutiny of 1857. He deals with the progressive and reactionary
movements from Sir Syed Ahmad Khan's time onwards, and the different phases of
the Moslem League]
The National Planning Committee
Towards the end of 1938 a National
Planning Committee was constituted at the instance of the Congress. It
consisted of fifteen members plus representatives of provincial governments and
such Indian states as chose to collaborate with us. Among the members were
well-known industrialists, financiers, economists, professors, scientists, as
well as representatives of the Trade Union Congress and the Village Industries
Association. The non-Congress Provincial Governments (Bengal, Punjab' and
Sind), as well as some of the major states (Hyderabad, Mysore, Baroda,
Travancore, Bhopal) co-operated with this committee. In a sense it was a
remarkably representative committee cutting across political boundaries as well
as the high barrier between official and non-official India—except for the fact
that the Government of India was not represented and took up a non-co-operative
attitude. Hard-headed big business was there as well as people who are called
idealists and doctrinaires, and socialists and near-communists. Experts and
directors of industries came from provincial governments and states.
It was a strange assortment of
different types and it was not clear how such an odd mixture would work. I
accepted the chair-manship of the committee not without hesitation and
misgiving; the work was after my own heart and I could not keep out of it.
Difficulties faced us at every turn.
There were not enough data for real planning and few statistics were available.
The Government of India was not helpful. Even the provincial governments,
though friendly and co-operative, did not seem to be particularly keen on
all-India planning and took only a distant interest in our work. They were far
too busy with their own problems and troubles. Important elements in the
Congress, under whose auspices the committee had come into existence, rather
looked upon it as an unwanted child, not knowing how it would grow up and
rather suspicious of its future activities. Big business was definitely
apprehensive and critical, and probably joined up because it felt that it could
look after its interests better from inside the committee than from outside.
It
was obvious also that any comprehensive planning could only take place under a
free national government, strong enough and popular enough to be in a position
to introduce fundamental changes in the social and economic structure. Thus the
attainment of national freedom and the elimination of foreign control became an
essential pre-requisite for planning. There were many other obstacles—our
social backwardness, customs, traditional outlook, etc.—but they had in any
event to be faced. Planning thus was not so much for the present, as for an
un ascertained future, and there was an air of unreality about it. Yet it had to
be based on the present and we hoped that this future was not a distant one. If
we could collect the available material, co-ordinate it, and draw up
blue-prints, we would prepare the ground for the real effective future
planning, meanwhile indicating to provincial governments and states the lines on
which they should proceed and develop their resources. The attempt to plan and
to see the various national activities—economic, social, cultural—fitting into
each other, had also a highly educative value for ourselves and the general
public. It made the people come out of their narrow grooves of thought and
action, to think of problems in relation to one another, and develop to some
extent at least a wider co-operative outlook.
The original idea behind the Planning
Committee had been to further industrialization—'the problems of poverty and
un-employment, of national defence and of economic regeneration in general
cannot be solved without industrialization. As a step towards such
industrialization, a comprehensive scheme of national planning should be formulated.
This scheme should provide for the development of heavy key industries, medium
scale industries, and cottage industries....' But no planning could possibly
ignore agriculture, which was the main stay of the people; equally important
were the social services. So one thing led to another and it was impossible to
isolate anything or to progress in one direction without corresponding progress
in another. The more we thought of this planning business, the vaster it grew
in its sweep and range till it seemed to embrace almost every activity. That
did not mean we intended regulating and regimenting everything, but we had to
keep almost everything in view even in deciding about one particular sector of
the plan. The fascination of this work grew upon me and, I think, upon the
other members of our committee also. But at the same time certain vagueness and
indefiniteness crept in; instead of concentrating on some major aspects of the
plan we tended to become diffuse. This also led to delay in the work of many of
our sub-committees which lacked the sense of urgency and of working for a
definite objective within a stated time.
Constituted as we were, it was not
easy for all of us to agree to any basic social policy or principles underlying
social organization. Any attempt to discuss these principles in the abstract
was bound to lead to fundamental differences of approach at the outset and
possibly to a splitting up of the committee. Not to have such a guiding policy
was a serious drawback, yet there was no help for it. We decided to consider
the general problem of planning as well as each individual problem concretely
and not in the abstract, and allow principles to develop out of such
considerations. Broadly speaking, there were two approaches: the socialist one aiming
at the elimination of the profit motive and emphasizing the importance of
equitable distribution, and the big business one striving to retain free
enterprise and the profit motive as far as possible, and laying greater stress
on production. There was also a difference in outlook between those who
favoured a rapid growth of heavy industry and others who wanted greater
attention to be paid to the development of village and cottage industries, thus
absorbing the vast number of the unemployed and partially employed. Ultimately
there were bound to be differences in the final conclusions. It did not very
much matter even if there were two or more reports, provided that all the
available facts were collected and co-ordinated, the common ground mapped out,
and the divergencies indicated. When the time came for giving effect to the
Plan, the then existing democratic government would have to choose what basic
policy to adopt. Meanwhile a great deal of essential preparation would have
been made and the various aspects of the problem placed before the public and
the various provincial and state governments.
Obviously we could not consider any
problem, much less plan, without some definite aim and social objective. That
aim was declared to be to ensure an adequate standard of living for the masses,
in other words, to get rid of the appalling poverty of the people. The
irreducible minimum, in terms of money, had been estimated by economists at
figures varying from Rs. 15 to Rs. 25 per capita per month. (These are
all pre-war figures.) Compared to western standards this was very low, and yet
it meant an enormous increase in existing standards in India. An approximate
estimate of the average annual income per capita was Rs. 65.
This included the rich and the poor, the town-dweller, and the villager. In
view of the great gulf between the rich and the poor and the concentration of
wealth in the hands of a few, the average income of the villager was estimated
to be far less, probably about Rs. 30 per capita per annum. These
figures bring home the terrible poverty of the people and the destitute
condition of the masses. There was lack of food, of clothing, of housing and of
every other essential requirement of human existence. To remove this lack and
ensure an irreducible minimum standard for everybody the national in-come had
to be greatly increased, and in addition to this increased production there had
to be a more equitable distribution of wealth. We calculated that a really
progressive standard of living would necessitate the increase of the national
wealth by 500 or 600 per cent. That was, however, too big a jump for us, and we
aimed at a 200 to 300 per cent increase within ten years.
We fixed a ten-year period for the
plan, with control figures for different periods and different sectors of
economic life.
Certain objective tests were also
suggested:
(1)
The improvement of nutrition—a balanced diet having a calorific value of 2,400
to 2,800 units for an adult worker.
(2)
Improvement in clothing from the then consumption of about fifteen yards to at
least thirty yards per capita per annum.
(3) Housing standards to reach at
least 100 square feet per capita.
Further, certain indices of progress
had to be kept in mind:
(i) Increase in agricultural
production, (ii) Increase in indus-trial production, (iii) Diminution of
unemployment, (iv) Increase in per capita income, (v) Liquidation of
illiteracy, (vi) Increase in public utility services, (vii) Provision of
medical aid on the basis of one unit for 1,000 population, (viii) Increase in
the average expectation of life.
The objective for the country as a
whole was the attainment, as far as possible, of national self-sufficiency.
International trade was certainly not excluded, but we were anxious to avoid
being drawn into the whirlpool of economic imperialism. We neither wanted to be
victims of an imperialist power nor to develop such tendencies ourselves. The
first charge on the country's produce should be to meet the domestic needs of
food, raw materials, and manufactured goods. Surplus production would not be
dumped abroad but used in exchange for such commodities as we might require. To
base our national economy on export markets might lead to conflicts with other
nations and to sudden upsets when those markets were closed to us.
So, though we did not start with a
well-defined social theory, our social objectives were clear enough and
afforded a common basis for planning. The very essence of this planning was a
large measure of regulation and co-ordination. Thus, while free enterprise was
not ruled out as such, its scope was severely restricted. In regard to defence
industries it was decided that they must be owned and controlled by the state.
Regarding other key industries, the majority were of opinion that they should
be state-owned, but a substantial minority of the committee considered that
state control would be sufficient. Such control, however, of these industries
had to be rigid. Public utilities, it was also decided, should be owned by some
organ of the state—either the Central Government, provincial government, or a
local board. It was suggested that something of the nature of the London
Transport Board might control public utilities. In regard to other important
and vital industries, no special rule was laid down but it was made clear that
the very nature of planning required control in some measure, which might vary
with the industry.
In
regard to the agency in state-owned industries it was sug-gested that as a
general rule an autonomous public trust would be suitable. Such a trust would
ensure public ownership and control and at the same time avoid the difficulties
and inefficiency which sometimes creep in under direct democratic control.
Co-operative ownership and control were also suggested for industries. Any
planning would involve a close scrutiny of the development of industry in all
its branches and a periodical survey of the progress made. It would mean also
the training of the technical staffs necessary for the further expansion of
industry, and the state might call upon industries to train such staffs.
The general principles governing land
policy were laid down: 'Agricultural land, mines, quarries, rivers, and forests
are forms of national wealth, ownership of which must vest absolutely in the
people of India collectively.' The co-operative principle should be applied to
the exploitation of land by developing collective and co-operative farms. It
was not proposed, however, to rule out peasant farming in small holdings, to
begin with at any rate, but no intermediaries of the type of talukdars,
zamindars, etc., should be recognized after the transition period was over. The
rights and title possessed by these classes should be progressively bought out.
Collective farms were to be started immediately by the state on culturable
waste land. Co-operative farming could be combined either with individual or
joint ownership. A certain latitude was allowed for various types to develop so
that, with greater experience, particular types might be encouraged more than
others.
We, or some of us at any rate, hoped
to evolve a socialized system of credit. If banks, insurance, etc., were not to
be nation-alized they should at least be under the control of the state, thus
leading to a state regulation of capital and credit. It was also desir-able to
control the export and import trade. By these various means a considerable
measure of state control would be established in regard to land as well as in
industry as a whole, though varying in particular instances, and allowing
private initiative to continue in a restricted sphere.
Thus, through the consideration of
special problems, we gradually developed our social objectives and policy.
There were gaps in them and occasional vagueness and even some contradiction;
it was far from a perfect scheme in theory. But I was agreeably surprised at the
large measure of unanimity achieved by us in spite of the incongruous elements
in our Committee. The big business element was the largest single group and its
outlook on many matters, especially financial and commercial, was definitely
conservative. Yet the urge for rapid progress, and the conviction that only
thus could we solve our problems of poverty and unemployment, were so great
that all of us were forced out of our grooves and compelled to think on new
lines. We had avoided a theoretical approach, and as each practical problem was
viewed in its larger context, it led us inevitably in a particular direction.
To me the spirit of co-operation of the members of the Planning Committee was
peculiarly soothing and gratifying, for I found it a pleasant contrast to the
squabbles and conflicts of politics. We knew our differences and yet we tried
and often succeeded, after discussing every point of view, in arriving at an
integrated conclusion which was accepted by all of us, or most of us.
Constituted as we were, not only in
our Committee but in the larger field of India, we could not then plan for
socialism as such. Yet it became clear to me that our plan, as it developed,
was inevitably leading us towards establishing some of the fundamentals of the
socialist structure. It was limiting the acquisitive factor in society,
removing many of the barriers to growth, and thus leading to a rapidly
expanding social structure. It was based on planning for the benefit cf the
common man, raising his standards greatly, giving him opportunities of growth,
and releasing an enormous amount of latent talent and capacity. And all this
was to be attempted in the context of democratic freedom and with a large
measure of co-operation of some at least of the groups who were normally
opposed to socialistic doctrine. That co-operation seemed to me worth while
even if it involved toning down or weakening the plan in some respects.
Probably I was too optimistic. But so long as a big step in the right direction
was taken, I felt that the very dynamics involved in the process of change
would facilitate further adaptation and progress. If conflict was inevitable,
it had to be faced; but if it could be avoided or minimized that was an obvious
gain. Especially as in the political sphere there was conflict enough for us
and, in the future, there might well be unstable conditions. A general consent
for a plan was thus of great value. It was easy enough to draw up blue-prints
based on some idealist conception. It was much more difficult to get behind
them that measure of general consent and approval which was essential for the
satisfactory working of any plan.
Planning, though inevitably bringing
about a great deal of control and co-ordination and interfering in some measure
with individual freedom, would, as a matter of fact, in the context of India
to-day, lead to a vast increase of freedom. We have very little freedom to
lose. We have only to gain freedom. If we adhered to the democratic state
structure and encouraged co-operative enterprises, many of the dangers of
regimentation and concentration of power might be avoided.
At our first sessions we had framed a
formidable questionnaire which was issued to various governments and public
bodies, universities, chambers of commerce, trade unions, research institutes,
etc. Twenty-nine sub-committees were also appointed to investigate and report
on specific problems. Eight of these sub-committees were for agricultural
problems; several were for industry; five for commerce and finance; two for
transport; two for education; two for public welfare; two for demographic
relations; and one for women's role in planned economy. There were in all about
350 members of these sub-committees, some of them overlapping. Most of them
were specialists or experts in their subjects—business-men, government, state,
and municipal employees, university professors or lecturers, technicians,
scientists, trade unionists, and police^ men. We collected in this way much of
the talent available in the country. The only persons who were not permitted to
co-operate with us, even when they were personally desirous of doing so, were
the officials and employees of the Government of India. To have so many persons
associated in our work was helpful in many ways. We had the advantage of their
special knowledge and experience, and they were led to think of their special
subject in relation to the wider problem. It also led to a greater interest in
planning all over the country. But these numbers were disadvantageous also, for
there was inevitable delay when busy people spread out all over a vast country
had to meet repeatedly.
I
was heartened to come into touch with so much ability and earnestness in all
departments of national activity, and these contacts added to my own education
greatly. Our method of work was to have an interim report from each
sub-committee, which the planning committee considered, approving of it or
partly criticizing it, and then sending it back with its remarks to the
sub-committee. A final report was then submitted out of which arose our
decisions on that particular subject. An attempt was being made continually to
co-ordinate the decisions on each sub-ject with those arrived at on other
subjects. When all the final reports had been thus considered and disposed of,
the Planning Committee was to review the whole problem in its vastness and
intricacy and evolve its own comprehensive report, to which the sub-committees'
reports would be added as appendices. As a matter of fact that final report was
gradually taking shape in the course of our consideration of the
sub-committees' reports.
There were irritating delays, chiefly
due to some of the sub-committees not keeping to the time-table fixed for them,
but on the whole we made good progress and got through an enormous amount of
work. Two interesting decisions were made in connection with education. We
suggested that definite norms of physical fitness for boys and girls be laid
down for every stage of education. We also suggested establishment of a system
of compulsory social or labour service, so as to make every young man and woman
contribute one year of his or her life, between the ages of eighteen and
twenty-two, to national utility, including agriculture, industry, public
utilities, and public works of all kinds. No exemption was to be allowed except
for physical or mental disability.
When World War II started in
September, 1939, it was suggested that the National Planning Committee should
suspend its activities. In November the Congress governments in the provinces
resigned and this added to our difficulties, for under the absolute rule of the
Governors in the provinces no interest was taken in our work. Business men were
busier than ever making money out of war requirements and were not so much
interested in planning.
The situation was changing from day to
day. We decided, however, to continue and felt that the war made this even more
necessary. It was bound to result in further industrialization, and the work we
had already done and were engaged in doing could be of great help in this
process. We were dealing then with our sub-committees' reports on engineering
industries, transport, chemical industries, and manufacturing industries, all
of the highest importance from the point of view of the war. But the Government
was not interested in our work and in fact viewed it with great disfavour.
During the early months of the war—the so-called 'phoney' period—their policy
was not to encourage the growth of Indian industry. Afterwards, the pressure of
events forced them to buy many of their requirements in India, but even so they
disapproved of any heavy industries being started there. Disapproval meant
virtual prohibition, for no machinery could be imported without government
sanction.
The Planning Committee continued its
work and had nearly finished dealing with its sub-committees' reports. We were
to finish what little remained of this work and then proceed to the consideration
of our own comprehensive report. I was, however, arrested in October, 1940, and
sentenced to a long term of imprisonment. Several other members of the Planning
Committee and its sub-committees were also arrested and sentenced. I was
anxious that the Planning Committee should continue to function and requested
my colleagues outside to do so. But they were not willing to work in the
Committee in my absence. I tried to get the Planning Committee's papers and
reports in prison so that I might study them and prepare a draft report. The
Government of India intervened and stopped this. No such papers were allowed to
reach me, nor were inter-views on the subject permitted.
So the National Planning Committee
languished, while I spent my days in jail. All the work we had done which,
though incomplete, could be used to great advantage for war purposes, remained
in the pigeon-holes of our office. I was released in December, 1941, and was
out of prison for some months. But this period was a hectic one for me, as it
was for others. All manner of new developments had taken place, the Pacific war
was on, India was threatened with invasion, and it was not possible then to pick
up the old threads and continue the unfinished work of the planning committee
unless the political situation cleared up. And then I returned to prison.
No comments:
Post a Comment